March 08, 2006

Point Shaving Occurs in 5% of NCAA Basketball Games with Large Spreads: So sayeth this paper from Justin Wolfers, an economist at the University of Pennsylvania. [via The Sports Economist]

posted by yerfatma to basketball at 12:45 PM - 31 comments

The upshot:

"Smaller favorites — teams favored by 12 or fewer points — beat the spread almost exactly 50 percent of the time, showing how good those oddsmakers are at their jobs. But heavy favorites cover in only 47 percent of their games. There is little chance that the difference is due to randomness."

posted by yerfatma at 12:47 PM on March 08, 2006

Good post, yerfatma. I'm a frequent visitor to The Sports Economist and was fascinated by the stuff in 'Freakonomics' (which my 10 year old is now reading - including the chapter on the economics of crack dealing in Chicago). I wouldn't have believed it was that common if not for the fact that (a) there are cases in the public domain where people have admitted to fixing games and (b) the stats back it up. I think it was Damon Runyon who said never to gamble on anything that could talk.

posted by owlhouse at 02:49 PM on March 08, 2006

This is really hard for me to stomach... 5%????

posted by everett at 02:49 PM on March 08, 2006

Steven Levitt apparently provided "feedback" for the paper. My first instinct was that higher spread games are harder to handicap, but the paper pretty demonstrated a bias towards the favorites failing to cover by just a few points. Now I'm wondering if the betting public is overestimating the the favorites in these lopsided games. But I'm skeptical that such a market inefficiency would still exist. Basically, I just don't want to think that 5% of high spread games are being fixed. I wonder if Wolfers would advocate systematically betting the underdogs for big spread games. I think the juice is too high for this to work, though.

posted by mbd1 at 03:10 PM on March 08, 2006

mbd1 - One of the articles that The Sports Economist ran recently was about backing home NFL teams playing a favoured team against the spread. They concluded from analysis of hundreds of games that this would be an effective betting strategy, as the spread represents what people think will be the result, and home field advantage isn't factored into people's betting approaches. However they noted that once this information was available publicly and in Vegas (i.e. the weight of money then reduces the spread) then you lose any advantage. You can't beat the bookie over the long run!

posted by owlhouse at 03:46 PM on March 08, 2006

Wow. Excellent post.

posted by rocketman at 05:00 PM on March 08, 2006

I don't think any sports are immune to this type of thing. The lure of money in society is too great for many, many people to resist, and thinking college athletes, with the backgrounds many of them come from, are beyond this, is naive. I wouldn't put it past players, coaches, or even schools to be involved when there's a chance to benefit financially. Just think of the things some people do for money.

posted by dyams at 06:00 PM on March 08, 2006

mbd1, I went through the same reactions as you, but I don't think they make sense (if I can remember my reasoning now). My versions of your theses were as follows: High-spread games may feature teams that do not play each other often, so comparative information about the teams is harder to come by, more likely to be biased. But the line is only initially set by Vegas. The efficiency of The Line is in the thousands of votes cast by bettors. There's no inherent reason why that should be less effective at different data points (unless there was a lack of data). Damnit, I forgot everything I was thinking about this earlier. The interesting thing would be to see what happens to the raw data as you redefine "heavy spreads". Which may be available in the paper. I should go check before I run my mouth.

posted by yerfatma at 06:46 PM on March 08, 2006

The author addresses the large spread issue starting around page 7:

"[O]verestimating the favorite’s ability would lead the peak of the distribution of outcomes for strong favorites to occur at outcomes in which the favorite barely fails to cover, with fewer strong favorites barely covering. This bias affects the whole distribution of outcomes, yielding directly testable implications. For instance, this bias should lead the spread to be a poor predictor of who wins the game, suggesting too few victories by strong favorites. The triangles in Figure 4 show the proportion of victories at different levels of the spread, again mapped against a baseline that assumes that the spread is an unbiased forecast with normal errors. These data provide no evidence that the spread overrates the ability of strong favorites; if anything, strong favorites (particularly strong home favorites) tend to win more often than suggested by the spread."

posted by yerfatma at 07:00 PM on March 08, 2006

I don't think any sports are immune to this type of thing. "Sports," yes, but my (perhaps naive) guess is that this type of thing is pretty much restricted to those on the collegiate level, where the profit margin for gamblers is much greater. The cost of getting even a peripheral player at the professional level to jeopardize his career for more money than they are already making seems to me to be so much less a profitable enterprise. Nobody here, including the article, indicated that this was going on at anywhere other than the college level, but it seems to be a point worth making. This is a good post, but I'm curious to know how the Spo-Fi sample of the sports community views this in the big picture of good/bad. Sure, the notion of college players taking money from gamblers can make your skin crawl, but this scenario on paper shows that the better teams are always beating the lesser teams legitimately. Gamblers are coming ahead, but only at the expense of other gamblers, so the imbalance is between "crooked" gamblers and "honest" gamblers. Couldn't one just write this off as caveat emptor on betting slips, and shrug that the integrity of the sport is scarcely nicked, wins and losses weighing the heaviest in the measure of "integrity?"

posted by BullpenPro at 07:01 PM on March 08, 2006

this type of thing is pretty much restricted to those on the collegiate level, where the profit margin for gamblers is much greater The NYT article addresses this directly. The profit margin for gamblers shouldn't be any different (am I missing something?), but basketball is easier for one player to fix and, as you suggest, you'd have to offer a big incentive to get pro athletes to throw a game. Couldn't one just write this off as caveat emptor on betting slips I think one could; I can't. First of all, I think I can speak for the Spofi Econ contingent when I say the skewing of real outcomes is distasteful in and of itself. Beyond that, I suppose it's a question of perception. Shorting the spread may lead to more dramatic moments, but I prefer my dramatic moments born of honesty. I watch sports to see the result when two people or groups give 100%. I want to know who wins when everybody is trying their best.

posted by yerfatma at 07:08 PM on March 08, 2006

this type of thing is pretty much restricted to those on the collegiate level, where the profit margin for gamblers is much greater The NYT article addresses this directly. The profit margin for gamblers shouldn't be any different (am I missing something?), but basketball is easier for one player to fix and, as you suggest, you'd have to offer a big incentive to get pro athletes to throw a game. Couldn't one just write this off as caveat emptor on betting slips I think one could; I can't. First of all, I think I can speak for the Spofi Econ contingent when I say the skewing of real outcomes is distasteful in and of itself. Beyond that, I suppose it's a question of perception. Shorting the spread may lead to more dramatic moments, but I prefer my dramatic moments born of honesty. I watch sports to see the result when two people or groups give 100%. I want to know who wins when everybody is trying their best.

posted by yerfatma at 07:09 PM on March 08, 2006

In relation to the caveat emptor thing - the 'fixing' of games is akin to insider trading on the stock exchange. That is, if a bookie or big gambler fixes a game, then they have an increased knowledge advantage. This is 'unfair', certainly, but is it 'illegal'? There are many people who think there is nothing wrong with insider trading and by logical extension, fixing games. All I know is that when I worked for a racecourse bookie (it paid my way through high school and university) he eventually went out of business because he wasn't big enough or connected enough to be in on the fixes. The big bookies (and some professional punters) prospered. I'm not an economist, but I'm pretty sure this isn't how 'the market' is supposed to work.

posted by owlhouse at 07:51 PM on March 08, 2006

Yerfatma, I liked your post so much I read it twice. The profit margin for gamblers shouldn't be any different (am I missing something?) My implication was that, for the gamblers involved for the fix -- assuming they would bet the same in every instance -- since the cost of a fix would be higher at the pro level, their overall profit from the game would be lower. When I said "good/bad" I didn't mean to imply that some people would consider this scenario "good" at all -- since the basic scenario is the difference between a 15 point game and a 12 point game, I don't think "dramatic moments" plays into this too much. I just wonder how "bad" this is to the average fan. Is it DefCon 5 bad? I doubt it. There is a sizable thread on the front page that addresses another "bad" issue (I don't want to say what for fear of leaving blood in the water) which I would guess rates a higher alert than this one (maybe not, but that's what I'm asking). You kind of make my point, though, when you say, "I want to know who wins when everybody is trying their best." You DO know, don't you, if the winning team is the only one that's letting up -- again, assuming that wins and losses constitute a high percentage of a game's "integrity." On review: Owlhouse, I see your point, but I think a large enough percentage of the population fail to see gambling as a legitimate "market." (Some people, I'm sure, feel the same about the stock market, but my belief is that that population is much smaller.) Gambling is borderline taboo -- straight-up taboo in some regions -- so the notion of upsetting that market may not be looked at with so much disdain.

posted by BullpenPro at 08:07 PM on March 08, 2006

but I think a large enough percentage of the population fail to see gambling as a legitimate "market." Right, but that's moral relativism, and I can't have any of that. If what the majority of people feel defined what was right, we'd be in a fine pickle.

posted by yerfatma at 06:08 AM on March 09, 2006

This is a great piece of work. The author suggests that the problem could be alleviated if against-the-spread betting went away, to be replaced by some kind of odds-based system a la horse racing. Would this significantly decrease, or increase the appeal of betting on basketball? For honest gamblers, I mean. TSE also mentions that the author is working on a similar analysis for pro ball, which should be interesting.

posted by Amateur at 07:18 AM on March 09, 2006

Would this significantly decrease, or increase the appeal of betting on basketball? For honest gamblers, I mean. Economically-speaking (if I'm capable of such a thing), it shouldn't change it at all. The information currently encoded in a game's spread would be moved to the payoff system, a la baseball betting, where you have to bet $300 to win $100 when Randy Johnson is pitching for the Yankees against Tampa Bay.

posted by yerfatma at 07:49 AM on March 09, 2006

The information currently encoded in a game's spread would be moved to the payoff system, a la baseball betting Sure, but in MLB the odds never get too far out of whack. When North Carolina plays East Bumfuck State University, EBSU has very close to zero probability of winning. I understand that that would lead to enormous payoffs, and in that sense the two systems are equivalent ... but that doesn't mean that the "market appeal" is the same to the bettors.

posted by Amateur at 09:06 AM on March 09, 2006

this article is complete bullshit. i can think of another reason why heavy favorites don't cover. vegas will stretch the point spread on "public" teams because it knows people will throw money at that team no matter what the spread. notre dame is an excellent example of a "public" team. duke is another. for this guy to state the only reason for the % difference HAS to be point shaving is ridiculous.

posted by ksb122 at 09:13 AM on March 09, 2006

i can think of another reason why heavy favorites don't cover. vegas will stretch the point spread on "public" teams . . . You realize the point of The Line is to set it to split the betting evenly between the two sides so Vegas makes money, right? No, you don't, otherwise you wouldn't suugest they regularly screw themselves on purpose. Let me suggest to you responding to an in-depth economic analysis with "this article is complete bullshit" and not backing up your hypothesis (such as it is) with evidence is not the way to foster healthy debate. When North Carolina plays East Bumfuck State University, EBSU has very close to zero probability of winning. Right, but betting has little to do with straight-up winning of contests. I take your point though; most likely those kinds of games would not be eligible for betting because they wouldn't draw enough action to even things out. No one is going to put down $10,000 to win $100. Well, not enough degenerates to make it risk-free for Vegas.

posted by yerfatma at 09:38 AM on March 09, 2006

Look you're all missing the point: Which 5%?!? How can I identify the oppotunities to profit from this most generous of trends? Poppa needs a new pair of shoes... to work the pedals on an Aston Martin.

posted by WeedyMcSmokey at 10:33 AM on March 09, 2006

Bet against a lot of teams favored by more than 12 points in college basketball games. </humorless>

posted by yerfatma at 11:32 AM on March 09, 2006

If what the majority of people feel defined what was right, we'd be in a fine pickle. Agreed, but I'm not building a case to make a law, I'm wondering how the majority of Spo-Fites measure this issue. There has been a lot of "this is right/this is wrong" but not as much "this is a huge deal/this is of minimal concern," which is what genuinely interests me. I'm not a gambler, but I'm not trying to make a moral judgment on gambling -- I'm trying to put some perspective on the issue as it relates to sports. Having said that, would an odds-based system become an incentive for gamblers to actually influence the outcome of the game rather than just shaving points? Or would the resulting betting behavior swing the odds such that it wouldn't make it worthwhile for the crooked gamblers?

posted by BullpenPro at 11:45 AM on March 09, 2006

would an odds-based system become an incentive for gamblers to actually influence the outcome of the game rather than just shaving points The incentive to influence outcomes is there for the gamblers regardless; but the odds-based system changes the net incentive for the players / coaches. Players and coaches are highly motivated (for various reasons) to win the game; they are not highly motivated to cover the spread, so a financial incentive can easily provide motivation not to.

posted by Amateur at 12:45 PM on March 09, 2006

Players and coaches are highly motivated (for various reasons) to win the game; they are not highly motivated to cover the spread This gets back to my "integrity of the game" question: if you remove the gamblers' ability to influence their outcome without influencing the outcome of the game, doesn't that give them additional incentive to rig game outcomes, so that the actual wins and losses (which I argue weigh heavily in the measure of "integrity") are effected more frequently? It's been stated that it is easier for the gamblers to work this point-shaving scheme than it is to fix games that have tight spreads, so presumably most of the fixes have no effect on wins and losses now. That changes when betting becomes all about game outcome and not just points scored.

posted by BullpenPro at 12:56 PM on March 09, 2006

if you remove the gamblers' ability to influence their outcome without influencing the outcome of the game, doesn't that give them additional incentive to rig game outcomes Yes, probably, but it's immaterial: if you change the betting to straight-up, you remove the incentive asymmetry* (he said, trying to justify the money his parents spent), which would require much larger offers to actors involved in the game to affect outcomes. The change in betting rules would not affect gamblers' incentives in any way, but it would drastically affect the actors' willingness to ever throw a game. *If you're a shady gambler and I'm a star player on a team favored by 12 points, your desires and mine match up in the space where my team wins by 1-11 points. Take away spread betting and they no longer match up.

posted by yerfatma at 03:02 PM on March 09, 2006

Agreed with yerfatma. Removing spread betting would cost the potential game-rigger more money to fix games, but wouldn't eliminate the possibility. However on the down side, spread betting encourages more people to bet in the first place, so I don't expect bookies or punters to request its removal, even if they run the risk of a fix now and then. I have no data to back me up on this, but base it on the psychology of the betting ring, gleaned from far too much time spent observing the human condition in those locations. And I love the word 'asymmetry'. I should have used it up above when I spoke of information advantage. 'Freakonomics' has a couple of chapters on information asymmetry, my favourite being why real estate agents are like the Ku Klux Klan.

posted by owlhouse at 03:41 PM on March 09, 2006

While I was initially upset by the idea that 5% of the games involve point shaving, I've come to a conclusion that I just don't care. And here is why: 1) The only people being hurt are those that gamble on sporting events. The players aren't hurt and the fans aren't hurt (assuming they are of the "hope my team wins" type and not the "hope my team covers the spread so I can make $50" type). 2) The only games that seem to suggest being fixed (big spread) are games where the fundamental outcome (win/loss) aren't affected. If you win by 14 or win by 11, it is still a win. Now, if games were being fixed that affected the outcome (win/loss), then I'd be upset. Okay, more upset, as this still bothers me a little bit. I still would have no problem with all of the players involved (if proven to shave points) to be banned from organized sports (professional or collegiate) for life. And I'd like to add my voice to those that encourage people to read "Freakonomics". As a "stats" guy, I loved it, but I think even those that are averse to statistics would find it an interesting read. And then follow it up with "The Tipping Point", another excellent book about trends and sociology.

posted by grum@work at 05:22 PM on March 09, 2006

Is it too indie rock of me to say I wanted more stats out of Freakonomics? I was kinda disappointed. The Tipping Point was a little more interesting; Malcolm Gladwell's books make me realize how much I like him as a magazine article writer. OTOH, grum, I demand you love Guns, Germs and Steel.

posted by yerfatma at 05:43 PM on March 09, 2006

And Collapse, Jared Diamond's latest. Shouldn't we form a book club?

posted by owlhouse at 06:31 PM on March 09, 2006

A book club just feels so damn white. Currently reading and enjoying (way too much) Consider the Lobster by David Foster Wallace. Next up are Chatter, which is about US eavesdropping with Echelon (someone sing out if they've read it and it sucks— I'll skip ahead to Gödel, Escher and Bach).

posted by yerfatma at 08:08 PM on March 09, 2006

You're not logged in. Please log in or register.